I voted for Ralph Nader in 2000. I was sick of the moderation of the Clinton administration, and wanted to send my message to the Democratic party. Part of my decision rested in knowing that as a resident of Portland, OR, my protest vote wouldn't really impact what was going to be a largely progressive local electorate; Gore took Oregon. However, since then, my thinking has changed. I'm not sure my views have become any more moderate. But I think they have become more expansive, in that they are more considerate of political - as well as social - realities.
I understand the aggravation with the two parties. Yet the
reality is that they each represent very different ideologies,
representative of huge portions of the American electorate. I don't see
how third parties change this. A parliamentary system might get more
representation, but ultimately, to get anything done there will still
have to be compromise, and coalitions will have to be whipped. Each of
the two parties could be broken into more ideologically specific groups,
but in the end they'd no doubt come together much as individual state
senators and congresspersons do.
This raises a larger question though, about compromise and working
across party lines. Having two parties might enforce ideological
rigidity. But I'm not sure. Contemporary polarization seems as much a
function of our cultural and media landscape as anything else. The less we ourselves become polarized, the less we will elect those who are. The question then, is how this happens.
A bastard's take on human behavior, politics, religion, social justice, family, race, pain, free will, and trees
Tuesday, December 27, 2011
Wednesday, December 21, 2011
Art and Suffering
Van Gogh -the quintessential tortured artist |
Hitchens’ prided himself on his honesty and his courage, so let’s honor his memory by facing up to the fact that his addictions to alcohol and tobacco are almost certainly why his life ended well before his time. The National Institutes of Health estimates that about 75% of esophageal cancers are caused by chronic heavy drinking. For people who are also addicted to tobacco (as Hitchens was) risk of this form of cancer is even higher than that grim statistic suggests.He then makes the fair point that art can be a crutch for addiction:
Many alcoholics would like to believe that their problem in life is something — anything — other than alcohol. To wit, there is a joke among Alcoholics Anonymous members about the guy who gets drunk for the thousandth time and wrecks his car, leading him to solemnly swear off driving. When we put into cultural discourse the myth that an alcoholic’s problem really isn’t alcohol, whether we want to or not we are feeding the denial of people who need to face some unpleasant facts, including that among a thousand other risks they are greatly increasing their risk of dying from cancer.
People in the arts and culture line often buy into the idea that active addictions fuel creativity, and it keeps many of them from trying to change. But there is no evidence that this fear has a rational basis; indeed just the opposite may be true. Bonnie Raitt said that what gave her the courage to admit her alcohol problem and put the plug in the jug was seeing that Stevie Ray Vaughn was an even more soulful and dazzling musician in his recovery than he was when he was loaded. And for what it’s worth, all the people I alluded to above were more successful (in some cases, to their own surprise) after they stopped drinking. Of course whether Hitchens would have been more or less successful as a writer and social critic if he had sobered up is (tragically) not something any of us can know, but that uncertainty is all the more reason to stop spreading that myth that recovery from addiction will invariably sap a creative alcoholic’s mojo.Society has always had a troubled relationship with artists. One the one hand, we are inspired by their often unconventional and vivacious ways. On the other, we turn our noses up at what often feels like their indulgent and juvenile behavior. The idea of the "tortured artist" is a trope that gives expression to both impulses. We want artists to bare their souls to us, but not as narcissists. That can be a hard distinction to make. Sometimes the former can only happen through the latter.
For what it is worth, the artists I’ve known have had to be quite brave in sacrificing much for their art. Most have given up on careers or stability in the hope that what they must believe is a talent will turn into something beautiful and successful. As more of an art-hobbyist myself, I feel like I truly appreciate the courage it must take to roll the dice like that. I was much too afraid of failure to make more of myself through my art. After all, you could spend decades working minimum wage jobs, scrimping and saving, just to support an art that most artists can only doubt is something great.
And what then, if you fail? You’re nearly forty years old and have little to show for your life but a handful of poorly received gallery shows, one or two quietly successful record albums known only to a handful of faithful fans, a publishing deal that you felt never got the media attention it deserved, etc. Many artists are indeed “tortured”, but sacrificing so much for your art can also be torturous. It shouldn’t be seen as indulgent, but rather a noble endeavor.
Hitchens appears to have indeed been an alcoholic, as well as a nicotine addict. But whether or not those vices were critical to his success is a counterfactual difficult to imagine. But what can be appreciated in him was not his success or specific achievements as a writer, but for his tenacity to do what he loved, to follow his dreams. Not all of us can say we've done as much.
Conservatism's Secret Logic
As Ron Paul surges in the polls, old questions arise about his involvement with racist publishing. A particularly ugly quote from one of the articles published in his newsletter:
Given the inefficiencies of what DC laughingly calls the criminal justice system, I think we can safely assume that 95 percent of the black males in that city are semi-criminal or entirely criminal.Paul denies culpability, but Ta-Nehisi Coates doesn't buy it.
Had I spent a decade stewarding an eponymous publication steeped in homophobia and anti-Semitism, I would not expect my friends and colleagues to accept an "I didn't write it"excuse.I really can't say I'm surprised by any of it. Much of conservatism is predicated on the same assumptions that would predicate racism. This is why it has always made perfect sense for there to be considerable overlap between racists and conservatives. I think the vast majority of conservatives despise the idea, yet privately rue the dogged logic that much of what they believe is entirely consistent with the racist cognitive framework. It’s a dirty truth, and the conservatives have two options: live in denial, or live dirty. The Ron Pauls, Pat Buchanans, Rush Limbaughs, Charles Murrays, etc. of the world have merely found themselves on the dirty end.
Monday, December 19, 2011
Broken Windows and Diamond Rings
An uncomfortable reality of political ideology is the degree to which any given stance is predicated at least in part on economic assumptions. Try as we might to corral a sense of objectivity and rationality into our views, at some point we must admit that there is just so much we do not know about the ways in which economies work. This, even as stark and fundamental disagreement can be found among leading economists.
So take, for instance, the controversial concept of government stimulus, which in our recent case represented close to a trillion dollars of federal spending. Projections have varied widely as to how stimulative it truly was, or could have been. As soon as you begin to look closely at the underlying arguments, it becomes clear that any lay understanding is woefully inaccurate in forming anything but a shallow and fragile understanding.
And so, it is with this admittedly devastating caveat, that I, intrepid blogger, attempt to carve into the following subject.
I've long wondered about the relative merit of various forms of economic activity, in terms of their effect on overall productivity. For instance, is a dollar spent on busfare to one's employer of more value than a dollar spent on a chocolate candy? My question follows largely from the fact that as wealth has become increasingly concentrated into the hands of the rich, there has no doubt been a subsequent shift in the types of economic activity, from utilitarian spending to luxury spending. Is the former type of spending better for overall growth? It would seem that to the degree that spending is non-utilitarian, it is wasteful, and thus not only distasteful in terms of a moral reckoning in what ought to be a more fair and equitable society - as a sort of ill-gotten decadence, but distasteful in purely economic terms, as a net drag on the economy.
On first glance, one might say that there should be no real difference. In each case, the dollar spent moves into the hands of another worker, who then uses it to purchase more goods and labor, and the production continues to be spread throughout the economy. Monies spent on chocolate will fill the pockets of the chocolatier, who in turn pays his workers, buys his cocoa, etc.
Yet what about this feeling that paying for chocolate is somehow decadent? It is certainly a luxury expense. But what does that really mean? No one will live or die because of it, unlike say basic food stuffs. But no will will live or die, either, because of money spent on busfare. Yet without it, considerable hardship might befall the rider; he may lose his job; he may have to purchase a car, leading to desperate sacrifices in other areas of his life. Maybe the best way to think about the issue is in terms of the productive possibilities of each form of spending. What are all the ways in which a bite of chocolate, by itself, contributes to productivity. It surely has some merit, in that it represents a reward, something to strive for that encourages hard work elsewhere. However this is a limited effect, and in many cases, certainly to the degree that its purchase has indeed been out of decadence, having long ago lost any meaningful pull on behavior, it could have as easily been done without. Again, this is luxury spending, by definition. Busfare cannot be done with in the same way. When we look at long-term drivers of productivity, we see things like the invention of the steam engine,the automobile, the internet. Chocolate, not so much. While there have no doubt been great innovations in luxury, their utility in encouraging productivity is conspicuously unaccounted for.
In 1850, French political economist Frédéric Bastiat wrote the following parable about economic activity and productivity. To economic theorists, it is known as The Broken Windows Fallacy.
My interest in the parable is also its illustration of hidden costs, although I'm more concerned with the effects of concentrated wealth and the hidden costs of luxury spending. To the extent that luxury spending is by itself almost entirely unproductive, and that concentrated wealth encourages it, one can argue that the concentration of wealth leads to, as Bastiat's parable might frame it, much broken glass. Better this wealth be put to productive use. Lord knows there is no lack of need for it in today's society.
Not only are there hidden costs to pointless consumer spending, or that which has little inherent value, but so too are there hidden costs in frivolous investment. I think it fair to claim that much of what caused the 2008 financial crisis was a direct outgrowth of sloppy investment: concentrated wealth led to overflowing pools of money, the manipulation of which was coordinated by greedy investment bankers who saw an opportunity to make enormous profits from money that was primed for recklessness by its decadent acquisition.
I recognize that I'm now far out of my comfort zone in understanding the Great Recession. But one can confidently make a couple of claims. Luxury spending and sloppy banking represent poor investments, and as such are defined by their hidden costs - their monies could have been put to more productive use. There will be many who point to the many government boondoggles as evidence of waste. The response to this is that there is plenty of good that government does (and often that which only government can do), and the larger controversy has likely much more to do with ideology and one's political and social preferences. But the Broken Windows Fallacy simply reminds us that there are always hidden costs to spending. These costs place spending in moral terms, that spending represents a choice between different net social outcomes. This is a choice we make both as individuals and as citizens of a democratic government.
So take, for instance, the controversial concept of government stimulus, which in our recent case represented close to a trillion dollars of federal spending. Projections have varied widely as to how stimulative it truly was, or could have been. As soon as you begin to look closely at the underlying arguments, it becomes clear that any lay understanding is woefully inaccurate in forming anything but a shallow and fragile understanding.
And so, it is with this admittedly devastating caveat, that I, intrepid blogger, attempt to carve into the following subject.
I've long wondered about the relative merit of various forms of economic activity, in terms of their effect on overall productivity. For instance, is a dollar spent on busfare to one's employer of more value than a dollar spent on a chocolate candy? My question follows largely from the fact that as wealth has become increasingly concentrated into the hands of the rich, there has no doubt been a subsequent shift in the types of economic activity, from utilitarian spending to luxury spending. Is the former type of spending better for overall growth? It would seem that to the degree that spending is non-utilitarian, it is wasteful, and thus not only distasteful in terms of a moral reckoning in what ought to be a more fair and equitable society - as a sort of ill-gotten decadence, but distasteful in purely economic terms, as a net drag on the economy.
On first glance, one might say that there should be no real difference. In each case, the dollar spent moves into the hands of another worker, who then uses it to purchase more goods and labor, and the production continues to be spread throughout the economy. Monies spent on chocolate will fill the pockets of the chocolatier, who in turn pays his workers, buys his cocoa, etc.
Yet what about this feeling that paying for chocolate is somehow decadent? It is certainly a luxury expense. But what does that really mean? No one will live or die because of it, unlike say basic food stuffs. But no will will live or die, either, because of money spent on busfare. Yet without it, considerable hardship might befall the rider; he may lose his job; he may have to purchase a car, leading to desperate sacrifices in other areas of his life. Maybe the best way to think about the issue is in terms of the productive possibilities of each form of spending. What are all the ways in which a bite of chocolate, by itself, contributes to productivity. It surely has some merit, in that it represents a reward, something to strive for that encourages hard work elsewhere. However this is a limited effect, and in many cases, certainly to the degree that its purchase has indeed been out of decadence, having long ago lost any meaningful pull on behavior, it could have as easily been done without. Again, this is luxury spending, by definition. Busfare cannot be done with in the same way. When we look at long-term drivers of productivity, we see things like the invention of the steam engine,the automobile, the internet. Chocolate, not so much. While there have no doubt been great innovations in luxury, their utility in encouraging productivity is conspicuously unaccounted for.
In 1850, French political economist Frédéric Bastiat wrote the following parable about economic activity and productivity. To economic theorists, it is known as The Broken Windows Fallacy.
Have you ever witnessed the anger of the good shopkeeper, James Goodfellow, when his careless son happened to break a pane of glass? If you have been present at such a scene, you will most assuredly bear witness to the fact that every one of the spectators, were there even thirty of them, by common consent apparently, offered the unfortunate owner this invariable consolation—"It is an ill wind that blows nobody good. Everybody must live, and what would become of the glaziers if panes of glass were never broken?"Bastiat's Fallacy is popular among Austrian economists, and those who favor small government. Their attraction is based on the parable's illustration of hidden costs; they believe that government spending is not zero sum and represents money that could not have been spent elsewhere. While this is true enough, what ultimately matters is the projected utility of the spending. Of course wasteful government spending is a net loss in productivity. Yet government spending that directs investment in a worthwhile investment that increases productivity, such as a bridge, or public school, is a net benefit.
Now, this form of condolence contains an entire theory, which it will be well to show up in this simple case, seeing that it is precisely the same as that which, unhappily, regulates the greater part of our economical institutions.
Suppose it cost six francs to repair the damage, and you say that the accident brings six francs to the glazier's trade—that it encourages that trade to the amount of six francs—I grant it; I have not a word to say against it; you reason justly. The glazier comes, performs his task, receives his six francs, rubs his hands, and, in his heart, blesses the careless child. All this is that which is seen.
But if, on the other hand, you come to the conclusion, as is too often the case, that it is a good thing to break windows, that it causes money to circulate, and that the encouragement of industry in general will be the result of it, you will oblige me to call out, "Stop there! Your theory is confined to that which is seen; it takes no account of that which is not seen."
It is not seen that as our shopkeeper has spent six francs upon one thing, he cannot spend them upon another. It is not seen that if he had not had a window to replace, he would, perhaps, have replaced his old shoes, or added another book to his library. In short, he would have employed his six francs in some way, which this accident has prevented.
My interest in the parable is also its illustration of hidden costs, although I'm more concerned with the effects of concentrated wealth and the hidden costs of luxury spending. To the extent that luxury spending is by itself almost entirely unproductive, and that concentrated wealth encourages it, one can argue that the concentration of wealth leads to, as Bastiat's parable might frame it, much broken glass. Better this wealth be put to productive use. Lord knows there is no lack of need for it in today's society.
Not only are there hidden costs to pointless consumer spending, or that which has little inherent value, but so too are there hidden costs in frivolous investment. I think it fair to claim that much of what caused the 2008 financial crisis was a direct outgrowth of sloppy investment: concentrated wealth led to overflowing pools of money, the manipulation of which was coordinated by greedy investment bankers who saw an opportunity to make enormous profits from money that was primed for recklessness by its decadent acquisition.
I recognize that I'm now far out of my comfort zone in understanding the Great Recession. But one can confidently make a couple of claims. Luxury spending and sloppy banking represent poor investments, and as such are defined by their hidden costs - their monies could have been put to more productive use. There will be many who point to the many government boondoggles as evidence of waste. The response to this is that there is plenty of good that government does (and often that which only government can do), and the larger controversy has likely much more to do with ideology and one's political and social preferences. But the Broken Windows Fallacy simply reminds us that there are always hidden costs to spending. These costs place spending in moral terms, that spending represents a choice between different net social outcomes. This is a choice we make both as individuals and as citizens of a democratic government.
Saturday, December 17, 2011
A Radical Reformation
Diane Ravitch evokes the grinchitude of Ebeneezer Scrooge as she compares the current ed reform movement to Dickens' callous crank. Reminding us that poverty is the real issue, she points to a new paper by Helen Ladd, professor of economics at Duke, "one of the nation's leading experts on issues of accountability". Mentioning that Ladd also co-authored an excellent opinion piece summarizing the paper in the NY Times, she quotes the abstract:
In the paper, Ladd proposes nothing new: "early-childhood and preschool programs; school-based health clinics and social services; after-school programs and summer programs". I have no problem with any of these ideas - all are sorely needed and crucial. But I don't see any of them, even taken as a whole, as being game changing.
The problem may be primarily in the way these programs get rolled out; each is mostly isolated from the rest, with no cohesive, comprehensive intervention in the specific family. This leads to a lot of families falling through the cracks, issues not being followed up on, and chronic problems not being treated. Providing targeted interventions in a family isn't easy, but it only becomes harder the more services stay segregated and don't coordinate.
An idea I've been kicking around for a few years is a sort of radical restructuring of public schools that organizes them less by geography (which is largely a proxy for income), than by rigorous human and social capital assessment.
Beginning at birth, parents would be required to take generalized assessments - residence, income, education, substance abuse history, mental illness, health, etc. These would trigger deeper assessments as needed. From this data, we begin to identify and target areas in which family interventions are required. This could begin with environmental interventions (paint, carpet, pollution, etc.) that seek to remove and reduce contaminants. There would also be home nurse visits, and targeted parenting classes, incentivized by special coupons either for extra services or rewards - maybe sponsored by community business groups.
Yet all of this would be highly centralized and continually monitored and assessed, triggering completion or addition of new services and classes. As the child develops, he would also be monitored for developmental progress and assigned requisite services. A central database would track the family in realtime, updating things like job status of immediate family and relatives, criminal offenses, enrollment in substance abuse programs, etc.
While all of this may seem like a sort of terribly invasive totalitarianism, its goal would always be to offer scaffolding for human and social capital development. Assessments would trigger gradual disengagement by the state as needed. Currently, the "nanny" state isn't doing a very good job meeting these families' needs. Yet social expenditures on education, interventions, policing and incarceration, are still necessary - yet not organized in a way that is ultimately very productive and transformational.
As the child develops and approaches the traditional age of Kindergarten enrollment, there would be a seamless integration between the K-12 system and pre-K. Based on continued family evaluation, the child would be placed in an elementary school not by location, but by need. As it stands, geography is already a pretty good proxy for human and social capital. But there would be more differentiation between schools, and yet not based arbitrarily on income/geography, but on real family evaluation data and criteria. What this would allow for is flexibility and much more highly focused intervention delivery. As such, depending on the level of interventions offered, these "schools" would function almost as family treatment centers, where a type of human and social capital triage would take place. Psychological services would be available 24 hours a day, parenting classes, daycare, fitness and enrichment, drug treatment, etc. would all be offered along-side traditional academic elementary classes.
Yet these classes wouldn't be exactly traditional. They would be staffed by experienced, highly paid, credentialed teachers trained in poverty intervention. Curriculum would be designed accordingly, accounting for cognitive and language deficits previously assessed for in the family database. Class sizes would be dramatically reduced, again according to needs assessment, to 10-15 students. Multiple aids would be available, each trained in various special needs of students.
A major benefit of such centralized "schools" (social service centers, really), would be the availability of community resources. I could think of fewer better interventions in a struggling community than for adults in rehab or probation to come and participate in reading groups with elementary or middle school children. So much of the dysfunction and nihilism we see in these communities is a direct result of the breakdown in community bonds and cross-generational engagement. Apart from reading groups, these mentors could function as volunteers in many areas of academic enrichment - PE, field trips, art, etc.
I anticipate the following objections to this radical conception of the merging of social services and education: cost, logistics, and intrusiveness. I'd like to see a projection of what such a system would cost. My guess is what it saves in consolidation of resources and increased productivity would alone pay for the added services. But long-term, the savings that would result from a dramatic targeting and investment in human and social capital would not only generate financial capital through a more effective and educated workforce, but it would also enormously reduce the expense of rehabilitation and incarceration.
As for logistics, I'm sure a variety of models could be experimented with. Federal funding could be made available that incentivizes competition and creative solutions, fostering inter and intra--state experimentation. In my work in social services, I can only see agencies welcoming the increased ability to do their work more effectively.
Intrusiveness might be the main sticking point for a lot of people. This sounds like big-government on steroids. But so are treatment facilities, police, prisons, and of course, schools. The reality is that poor communities need our help. Their lack of human and social capital defines their need for help and intervention. To the degree that a family demonstrates no need for services, none will be necessary. I think if you asked poor families themselves, they would jump at the chance for better health care, better education, better daycare, and generally more support to be successful.
Current U.S. policy initiatives to improve the U.S. education system, including No Child Left Behind, test-based evaluation of teachers and the promotion of competition, are misguided because they either deny or set to the side a basic body of evidence documenting that students from disadvantaged households on average perform less well in school than those from more advantaged families. Because these policy initiatives do not directly address the educational challenges experienced by disadvantaged students, they have contributed little—and are not likely to contribute much in the future—to raising overall student achievement or to reducing achievement and educational attainment gaps between advantaged and disadvantaged students. Moreover, such policies have the potential to do serious harm. Addressing the educational challenges faced by children from disadvantaged families will require a broader and bolder approach to education policy than the recent efforts to reform schools.While this is an excellent argument for why reform efforts are misguided and naive, it fails to offer a compelling alternative. I applaud the critique of current ed reform, but I would like to see more proposals for how this translates into policies that truly transform our broken system and address the many issues that ed reform does not.
In the paper, Ladd proposes nothing new: "early-childhood and preschool programs; school-based health clinics and social services; after-school programs and summer programs". I have no problem with any of these ideas - all are sorely needed and crucial. But I don't see any of them, even taken as a whole, as being game changing.
The problem may be primarily in the way these programs get rolled out; each is mostly isolated from the rest, with no cohesive, comprehensive intervention in the specific family. This leads to a lot of families falling through the cracks, issues not being followed up on, and chronic problems not being treated. Providing targeted interventions in a family isn't easy, but it only becomes harder the more services stay segregated and don't coordinate.
An idea I've been kicking around for a few years is a sort of radical restructuring of public schools that organizes them less by geography (which is largely a proxy for income), than by rigorous human and social capital assessment.
Beginning at birth, parents would be required to take generalized assessments - residence, income, education, substance abuse history, mental illness, health, etc. These would trigger deeper assessments as needed. From this data, we begin to identify and target areas in which family interventions are required. This could begin with environmental interventions (paint, carpet, pollution, etc.) that seek to remove and reduce contaminants. There would also be home nurse visits, and targeted parenting classes, incentivized by special coupons either for extra services or rewards - maybe sponsored by community business groups.
Yet all of this would be highly centralized and continually monitored and assessed, triggering completion or addition of new services and classes. As the child develops, he would also be monitored for developmental progress and assigned requisite services. A central database would track the family in realtime, updating things like job status of immediate family and relatives, criminal offenses, enrollment in substance abuse programs, etc.
While all of this may seem like a sort of terribly invasive totalitarianism, its goal would always be to offer scaffolding for human and social capital development. Assessments would trigger gradual disengagement by the state as needed. Currently, the "nanny" state isn't doing a very good job meeting these families' needs. Yet social expenditures on education, interventions, policing and incarceration, are still necessary - yet not organized in a way that is ultimately very productive and transformational.
As the child develops and approaches the traditional age of Kindergarten enrollment, there would be a seamless integration between the K-12 system and pre-K. Based on continued family evaluation, the child would be placed in an elementary school not by location, but by need. As it stands, geography is already a pretty good proxy for human and social capital. But there would be more differentiation between schools, and yet not based arbitrarily on income/geography, but on real family evaluation data and criteria. What this would allow for is flexibility and much more highly focused intervention delivery. As such, depending on the level of interventions offered, these "schools" would function almost as family treatment centers, where a type of human and social capital triage would take place. Psychological services would be available 24 hours a day, parenting classes, daycare, fitness and enrichment, drug treatment, etc. would all be offered along-side traditional academic elementary classes.
Yet these classes wouldn't be exactly traditional. They would be staffed by experienced, highly paid, credentialed teachers trained in poverty intervention. Curriculum would be designed accordingly, accounting for cognitive and language deficits previously assessed for in the family database. Class sizes would be dramatically reduced, again according to needs assessment, to 10-15 students. Multiple aids would be available, each trained in various special needs of students.
A major benefit of such centralized "schools" (social service centers, really), would be the availability of community resources. I could think of fewer better interventions in a struggling community than for adults in rehab or probation to come and participate in reading groups with elementary or middle school children. So much of the dysfunction and nihilism we see in these communities is a direct result of the breakdown in community bonds and cross-generational engagement. Apart from reading groups, these mentors could function as volunteers in many areas of academic enrichment - PE, field trips, art, etc.
I anticipate the following objections to this radical conception of the merging of social services and education: cost, logistics, and intrusiveness. I'd like to see a projection of what such a system would cost. My guess is what it saves in consolidation of resources and increased productivity would alone pay for the added services. But long-term, the savings that would result from a dramatic targeting and investment in human and social capital would not only generate financial capital through a more effective and educated workforce, but it would also enormously reduce the expense of rehabilitation and incarceration.
As for logistics, I'm sure a variety of models could be experimented with. Federal funding could be made available that incentivizes competition and creative solutions, fostering inter and intra--state experimentation. In my work in social services, I can only see agencies welcoming the increased ability to do their work more effectively.
Intrusiveness might be the main sticking point for a lot of people. This sounds like big-government on steroids. But so are treatment facilities, police, prisons, and of course, schools. The reality is that poor communities need our help. Their lack of human and social capital defines their need for help and intervention. To the degree that a family demonstrates no need for services, none will be necessary. I think if you asked poor families themselves, they would jump at the chance for better health care, better education, better daycare, and generally more support to be successful.
Monday, December 5, 2011
Ruin Porn
In the mid-1990's I had a job delivering meals and groceries to people living with AIDS in San Francisco. Much of my job was spent filling in the gaps that volunteers could not cover. In our office, we had a map of the city, with pushpins marking all our clients. Far and away, the highest concentrations were clustered in areas of high poverty, especially the Tenderloin district, where single-occupancy-residencies (SRO's) were common.
These were tall buildings, often eight or nine stories, usually managed by an immigrant family on the first floor, protected by a cage and responsible for regulating entry into and out of the building. The buildings were old, likely nearly a century, but they had fallen into deep disrepair. The clunky elevators with manual gates would often break down; paint was peeling; carpets were torn and stained; trash piled up at smelly chutes that dripped with grime. There was air of dingy lawlessness and danger, occupants ranged from the old and infirm to young and drug-addicted, deeply psychotic to suspiciously sociopathic. Many of my clients had a triple-diagnosis: drug abusing, mentally ill, and HIV positive. Many of them came from poverty, and AIDS was merely a bi-product of their lifestyle. But many had lost it all, and gone there to die.
A girlfriend at the time had an artist friend in LA whose work was appearing in a local gallery. I was taken back a bit when I saw where the gallery was located - Fifth street, two blocks south of Market, the heart of the Tenderloin, where I worked on a daily basis. I had gotten used to many of the locals, and as we walked towards the gallery, I began to recognize some of their faces. Off the clock, on a Sunday afternoon, their lives were no longer my work, they were now my fellow citizens. I had punched out a long time ago, yet they were still here, wandering the same stretch of sidewalk, muttering the same laments, hiding from the same predatory gangsters and back-alley villains, clutching the same dirty cigarettes.
It made sense when we entered the gallery. It was a minimal space, essentially a bare storefront stripped of any refurbishment. Concrete and cracked tile floors, stained walls and rusty, leaking plumbing jutting from the ceiling. I don't recall what the art was, but it was bleak - photographs I think. The desperation and sadness of the gallery environment reinforced the intended sentiment.
Yet for me, it reinforced something else. It pained me to be existing in a state of mind, a state of conscious experience that not only was in close proximity to such tragic suffering, but that was being asked to actively benefit from it. Like blood money is the profit from violence, one might call this blood art, as it was profiting from a kind of violence done to a community.
A term for this phenomenon has been coined: ruin porn. I'm not sure where it first came from, but it seems closely tied to the popularity of art created around the decrepitude of Detroit. French photographers Yves Marchand and Romain Meffre published a photo essay in Time entitled Detroit's Beautiful, Horrible Decline.
It isn't an inaccurate title. The photographs are beautiful. The subject is terribly sad. An obvious commentary is central to the work: a fall from grace. Just what has fallen, and maybe more importantly, why it has fallen, is left to the viewer to ponder. On the blog Hyperallergic, Kyle Chayka reminds us that ruin porn is nothing new. Art has long been concerned with death and decay. As long as architecture has been made, its inevitable slow collapse has been documented.
But that's part of the problem. A class distinction runs right through this work. When I visited the Tenderloin art gallery, I did not have to live there. I was attending college part time; I went home to a clean, safe neighborhood; I had the luxury of taking the 10,000ft. view. With the coolness of a mortician, my palate for art appreciation was cleansed and prepped by an invisible, yet indispensable privilege.
Marie Antoinette, in the final days before her execution, was living behind walls of sublime ignorance, inhabiting a decadence in sharp contrast to the common citizenry. Many false rumors were spread of her, promoting an inflated sense of her greed and debauchery. Yet even these rumors never suggested that she might be taking pleasure in the "beautiful" demise of her country.
We, elite as we may be in our appreciation of high art and cultural criticism, are neither kings nor queens. Most of us would surely like to help those who must live with the consequences of ruin and decay. Part of the beauty we see in this art surely comes from its satiation of a deep anxiety that all members of the modern world feel. There is a sense of alienation, loneliness in modern civilization, in which one must at all times grapple with two distinct realities of our consciousness: that of our family, friends and relations, and that of the anonymous, unknown public with whom we share so much, yet of whom we know so little.
In this art we see an expression of the promise we all feel in our daily lives as we make our way through work, traffic, public engagement, digestion of current events and our identity as reflected in endlessly changing times; the ruin has come to what had once possessed so much promise: the carefully laid brick, measured and tailored edges, artfully designed color pallets and purposeful textures.
But then we see the promise destroyed. Just as our hopes and dreams seem so often seem precariously balanced on the edge not only of disaster in the form of horrible accidents, lost jobs or political defenestration, but more reliably, the simple, gradual lowering of expectations as hopes and dreams gradually slip away, steadily crushed by the weight of time and responsibility, dying the death of a thousand cuts. There is a truth here that we are proud to see exposed. Life's edges, perfect as we can ever plan them to be, will inevitably have a roughness that we cannot deny. Death is a part of living.
All of this is good. It is what art is for. But as we gaze at our respective navels, there is a world of hurt more tragic happening to people just outside this frame. We cannot allow ourselves to indulge our own private narratives on the backs of such suffering, exploiting its demonry for our own private exorcisms. We must be reminded that art can be a useful and profound representation, but that for so many, it is not a representation, but a reality.
These were tall buildings, often eight or nine stories, usually managed by an immigrant family on the first floor, protected by a cage and responsible for regulating entry into and out of the building. The buildings were old, likely nearly a century, but they had fallen into deep disrepair. The clunky elevators with manual gates would often break down; paint was peeling; carpets were torn and stained; trash piled up at smelly chutes that dripped with grime. There was air of dingy lawlessness and danger, occupants ranged from the old and infirm to young and drug-addicted, deeply psychotic to suspiciously sociopathic. Many of my clients had a triple-diagnosis: drug abusing, mentally ill, and HIV positive. Many of them came from poverty, and AIDS was merely a bi-product of their lifestyle. But many had lost it all, and gone there to die.
A girlfriend at the time had an artist friend in LA whose work was appearing in a local gallery. I was taken back a bit when I saw where the gallery was located - Fifth street, two blocks south of Market, the heart of the Tenderloin, where I worked on a daily basis. I had gotten used to many of the locals, and as we walked towards the gallery, I began to recognize some of their faces. Off the clock, on a Sunday afternoon, their lives were no longer my work, they were now my fellow citizens. I had punched out a long time ago, yet they were still here, wandering the same stretch of sidewalk, muttering the same laments, hiding from the same predatory gangsters and back-alley villains, clutching the same dirty cigarettes.
It made sense when we entered the gallery. It was a minimal space, essentially a bare storefront stripped of any refurbishment. Concrete and cracked tile floors, stained walls and rusty, leaking plumbing jutting from the ceiling. I don't recall what the art was, but it was bleak - photographs I think. The desperation and sadness of the gallery environment reinforced the intended sentiment.
Yet for me, it reinforced something else. It pained me to be existing in a state of mind, a state of conscious experience that not only was in close proximity to such tragic suffering, but that was being asked to actively benefit from it. Like blood money is the profit from violence, one might call this blood art, as it was profiting from a kind of violence done to a community.
A term for this phenomenon has been coined: ruin porn. I'm not sure where it first came from, but it seems closely tied to the popularity of art created around the decrepitude of Detroit. French photographers Yves Marchand and Romain Meffre published a photo essay in Time entitled Detroit's Beautiful, Horrible Decline.
"St. Margaret Mary School" - Yves Marchand and Romain Meffre |
It isn't an inaccurate title. The photographs are beautiful. The subject is terribly sad. An obvious commentary is central to the work: a fall from grace. Just what has fallen, and maybe more importantly, why it has fallen, is left to the viewer to ponder. On the blog Hyperallergic, Kyle Chayka reminds us that ruin porn is nothing new. Art has long been concerned with death and decay. As long as architecture has been made, its inevitable slow collapse has been documented.
"Architectural momento mori exist as well in ruin porn from centuries ago. Think we came up with anything new, shooting cavernous disused spaces? These photographers would do well to catch up on their Piranesi, an 18th century architect and printmaker whose etchings of the ruins of Rome are staggeringly epic, baroquely detailed and tragically decayed, a clear forerunner to the visual language of the Detroit photographers."Yet the ruins of Rome evidence a tragedy that occurred centuries ago, to people many generations past. What happens when the tragedy is taking place all around us? Granted, most of the viewers of ruin porn will not have lived in these neighborhoods. It isn't as if they are being entertained by the suffering of their neighbors.
But that's part of the problem. A class distinction runs right through this work. When I visited the Tenderloin art gallery, I did not have to live there. I was attending college part time; I went home to a clean, safe neighborhood; I had the luxury of taking the 10,000ft. view. With the coolness of a mortician, my palate for art appreciation was cleansed and prepped by an invisible, yet indispensable privilege.
Marie Antoinette, in the final days before her execution, was living behind walls of sublime ignorance, inhabiting a decadence in sharp contrast to the common citizenry. Many false rumors were spread of her, promoting an inflated sense of her greed and debauchery. Yet even these rumors never suggested that she might be taking pleasure in the "beautiful" demise of her country.
We, elite as we may be in our appreciation of high art and cultural criticism, are neither kings nor queens. Most of us would surely like to help those who must live with the consequences of ruin and decay. Part of the beauty we see in this art surely comes from its satiation of a deep anxiety that all members of the modern world feel. There is a sense of alienation, loneliness in modern civilization, in which one must at all times grapple with two distinct realities of our consciousness: that of our family, friends and relations, and that of the anonymous, unknown public with whom we share so much, yet of whom we know so little.
In this art we see an expression of the promise we all feel in our daily lives as we make our way through work, traffic, public engagement, digestion of current events and our identity as reflected in endlessly changing times; the ruin has come to what had once possessed so much promise: the carefully laid brick, measured and tailored edges, artfully designed color pallets and purposeful textures.
But then we see the promise destroyed. Just as our hopes and dreams seem so often seem precariously balanced on the edge not only of disaster in the form of horrible accidents, lost jobs or political defenestration, but more reliably, the simple, gradual lowering of expectations as hopes and dreams gradually slip away, steadily crushed by the weight of time and responsibility, dying the death of a thousand cuts. There is a truth here that we are proud to see exposed. Life's edges, perfect as we can ever plan them to be, will inevitably have a roughness that we cannot deny. Death is a part of living.
All of this is good. It is what art is for. But as we gaze at our respective navels, there is a world of hurt more tragic happening to people just outside this frame. We cannot allow ourselves to indulge our own private narratives on the backs of such suffering, exploiting its demonry for our own private exorcisms. We must be reminded that art can be a useful and profound representation, but that for so many, it is not a representation, but a reality.
Sunday, December 4, 2011
The Retribution Mistake
Pedophilia I think is a perfect example of this. As far as we know, it can't be cured; it seems to be a sexual preference (for prepubescent children) much like hetero or homosexuality. While different therapies can somewhat limit the behavior, the impulse will always be there.
In discussions of determinism, both sides should be able to agree that there are at least limitations on freedom; people will always have different capacities for behavior, whether genetic or learned. Pedophilia seems likely to have a genetic root. It therefore makes sense to at least have some compassion for people who have been born into a body that, due to a design flaw, makes them want to do bad things to children.
In embracing a determinist outlook, I think it is reasonable to suppose that were society at large to move in that direction, much of the stigma surrounding pedophilia would fade, and pedophiles would be more able to "come out", as it were, and volunteer for treatment. There would still be harsh penalties for offenses, as a deterrent, but otherwise people would be considered mentally ill and "prone to violence".
I think of those who argue for social retribution, in which there isn't an emotional satiation claimed, but rather a sort of "social evening"; I understand it to be a sense that the wrong committed needs to be corrected for through punishment, at the most extreme being a death sentence. The calculation seems to be made under the assumption that the individual made a choice. Would retribution still apply if the individual had no choice. A better example might be if someone had a brain tumor that destroyed his sense of empathy, turning him from an otherwise kind person into a murderer?
In other words, if the notion of choice were removed, would the desire for retribution still exist? Is there a point where retribution no longer seems appropriate? Looking at violent attacks by animals, many feel that retribution is necessary, even if the animal - a bear say, or puma - was merely behaving naturally, and could be set free into the wild. This notion seems to stretch the concept.
But I think it might argue against the concept of social retribution. For even assuming that to the degree that no personal impulse towards retribution exists in such cases, the argument could still hold that a wrong has been done against society, and must be "paid for". Of course, the debtor is a wild animal. When a tree crushes a family in their home, a wrong has also been done against society. Yet seeking retribution on the tree would be absurd.
Or would it? How much of a difference is there really between individual bloodlust and the concept of social retribution? The former seems highly biased, and therefor distasteful, but how much is the latter, seemingly more calm and rationally considered, not merely a different version of that same impulse? Human nature has been shown over and over to suffer from very peculiar and emotionally driven impulses, even in the total abstract.
Experimental studies have found all kinds of evidence for the ways in which our decisions are guided by impulses we are not even aware of. For instance, the study in which people refused to put on a jacket that was told was once worn by Hitler. Or our tendency in the trolley car experiment to greatly favor those close to us as opposed to those further away. I mention these not to necessarily illustrate that these are wrong feelings, or that we should feel them, but that they can lead us to illogical premises and bad policy outcomes.
What becomes difficult is in determining just how much this bias is at work in our thinking - especially concerning bigger philosophical issues in which it isn't clear where our thinking - our "preference" - is really coming from; in this way, politics and philosophy can be like a matter of taste, where we just "know it when we see it". I can't say for certain that the concept of social retribution is based upon a biased sense of justice - that it is more a matter of personal taste than reason - but I can see how it might be.
Saturday, December 3, 2011
The Reality of "Choice"
Gail Collins writes about the growth of online K-12 charter schools, the most successful being for-profit K-12, Inc.
Having taught at a charter school with a major emphasis on homeschooling, and that was increasingly moving towards an online model, I can speak to some of the concerns people have about these schools. There was little transparency in terms of how the school was run, and financed its activities. This is a critique of charter schools in general, removed as they are from conventional public school accountability. This was especially concerning to me, as I worked at one of the satellite campuses, which was located in a poor neighborhood and drew from a largely disadvantaged population. I worried that the students' needs were not being met and being given short-shrift by the charter's more middle-class, home-schooled demographic priorities.
Another concern people have with online programs is that they'll further inhibit poor brick and mortar schools' ability to serve the special needs of their populations. As with brick and mortar charters, they will further siphon off the families with means, leaving behind the families with the fewest resources. The poor are often thought of as a homogeneous demographic, defined only by financial capital. But in reality there exists a great diversity of means, in terms of human and social capital, the efficacy of individual parenting, family education levels, issues with substance abuse or criminality, etc. Statistically, only a very small percentage of poor parents have been actively trying to get their children into charter schools as alternatives to traditional public schools. These are the parents who would be raising higher performing students, and realize that their students are being subjected to the many negative social pressures and forces at work in ghettos. This is simply a function of geography and property values.
The effect of this movement of high-capital families out of poor schools is to further segregate communities by means. While certainly a great benefit to those who know how to take advantage of the process, those left behind are further isolated and concentrated in their disadvantage. For instance, an average poor classroom might have 20% of its students suffering from emotional, behavioral, and academic deficits owing to severe neglect and strife at home, and another 20% enjoying the benefits of a cognitively stimulating and loving environment at home, able to complete work and be actively engaged in positive learning. In a class of 30-35 students, this presents an enormous challenge for a teacher in differentiating his instruction to adequately meet the needs of every child. In removing the top 20% of students, you are essentially (if my math is correct) removing 100% of the highest performers, in return for a 5% increase in the lowest and 15% increase in middle performers.
Now, in a perfect world, this may not be the worst thing. There are many advantages to less differentiation, or more homogeneity in a classroom. With a smaller range of needs, the teacher is better able to manage his instructional specificity. At the site level, resources can be more focused and delivered more efficiently. Unfortunately, this doesn't really happen. The poor have a tendency to get neglected. In the classroom, more low-performing students means more interruptions, more truancy, more remediation, lower standards, and greater teacher burnout. Class sizes remain the same, only increasing the teacher's burden. At the site level, while more services are often offered, the decline in parent means translates into less local community resources, and more demand for interventions, requiring ever more services and attention. Socially, the negative pressures are reinforced, while the positive pressures are reduced. Net negativity is thus increased.
It doesn't have to be this way. If class sizes were reduced, more services were offered, and resources were made available for teachers and staff to leverage, you would have a system in which high concentrations of disadvantage and dysfunction were ripe for efficient, targeted intervention. Yet the system would have to be designed to support this extra burden. From the ground floor up, it would take into account the population's special needs, and not expect teachers to primarily bear the burden. Currently, "teacher accountability" is frequently mentioned, but more rarely is "systemic accountability". Where is the accountability when systems are in place that shovel highly needy, at-risk populations into traditional classroom environments. It is as if schools, teachers and students are set-up to fail.
I would not be as skeptical of educational innovations such as charter schools or online programs, if they were understood in the context of larger socioeconomic issues in education. For many poor parents, online schooling might make the most sense, and be a good fit for their child's needs. For many others, their children's needs may be better served by an environment that can set the bar higher, knowing that students will be able to competently meet it, as opposed to simply being set-up for failure.
I've long thought a rigorous socio-economic assessment regime could be designed that measures and then places families into school settings designed to appropriately meet their specific needs. To me, this is truly what "choice" looks like. It isn't bottom-up, in terms of parents being "allowed" to send their children wherever they like. But that concept assumes that poor families are homogeneous in their ability to best see to their children's development. The reality is that many poor families need top-down help, and giving them "choice" is a false notion, implying that poor performing families are "choosing" not to be successful. Everyone wants to be successful, even the families struggling with poor parenting skills, single-parenthood, substance abuse, etc. But they don't know how. The sad reality is that we only have two choices when it comes to many poor families - the nanny state, or the neglectful parent state. Contrary to the fantasies we would like to believe about human behavior, reality is that, due to the many disadvantages and behavioral constraints besetting poor communities, owing to numerous historical and systemic factors, we are in a position of "parenthood", in that if left to fend for themselves, too many families - and their children - will not be successful. That is the reality. That is the reality of "choice".
"...a big private online education business. It was founded by a
former Goldman Sachs banker and by William Bennett, the Republican
writer and talk-show host, with an infusion of cash from the former
disgraced junk-bond king Mike Milken. Its teachers generally work from
their homes, communicating with their students by e-mail or phone. (At
one point in Arizona, essays of students attending an online academy run
by K12 were outsourced to India for correction. K12 says the program
was a pilot and was discontinued.)"
Having taught at a charter school with a major emphasis on homeschooling, and that was increasingly moving towards an online model, I can speak to some of the concerns people have about these schools. There was little transparency in terms of how the school was run, and financed its activities. This is a critique of charter schools in general, removed as they are from conventional public school accountability. This was especially concerning to me, as I worked at one of the satellite campuses, which was located in a poor neighborhood and drew from a largely disadvantaged population. I worried that the students' needs were not being met and being given short-shrift by the charter's more middle-class, home-schooled demographic priorities.
Another concern people have with online programs is that they'll further inhibit poor brick and mortar schools' ability to serve the special needs of their populations. As with brick and mortar charters, they will further siphon off the families with means, leaving behind the families with the fewest resources. The poor are often thought of as a homogeneous demographic, defined only by financial capital. But in reality there exists a great diversity of means, in terms of human and social capital, the efficacy of individual parenting, family education levels, issues with substance abuse or criminality, etc. Statistically, only a very small percentage of poor parents have been actively trying to get their children into charter schools as alternatives to traditional public schools. These are the parents who would be raising higher performing students, and realize that their students are being subjected to the many negative social pressures and forces at work in ghettos. This is simply a function of geography and property values.
The effect of this movement of high-capital families out of poor schools is to further segregate communities by means. While certainly a great benefit to those who know how to take advantage of the process, those left behind are further isolated and concentrated in their disadvantage. For instance, an average poor classroom might have 20% of its students suffering from emotional, behavioral, and academic deficits owing to severe neglect and strife at home, and another 20% enjoying the benefits of a cognitively stimulating and loving environment at home, able to complete work and be actively engaged in positive learning. In a class of 30-35 students, this presents an enormous challenge for a teacher in differentiating his instruction to adequately meet the needs of every child. In removing the top 20% of students, you are essentially (if my math is correct) removing 100% of the highest performers, in return for a 5% increase in the lowest and 15% increase in middle performers.
Now, in a perfect world, this may not be the worst thing. There are many advantages to less differentiation, or more homogeneity in a classroom. With a smaller range of needs, the teacher is better able to manage his instructional specificity. At the site level, resources can be more focused and delivered more efficiently. Unfortunately, this doesn't really happen. The poor have a tendency to get neglected. In the classroom, more low-performing students means more interruptions, more truancy, more remediation, lower standards, and greater teacher burnout. Class sizes remain the same, only increasing the teacher's burden. At the site level, while more services are often offered, the decline in parent means translates into less local community resources, and more demand for interventions, requiring ever more services and attention. Socially, the negative pressures are reinforced, while the positive pressures are reduced. Net negativity is thus increased.
It doesn't have to be this way. If class sizes were reduced, more services were offered, and resources were made available for teachers and staff to leverage, you would have a system in which high concentrations of disadvantage and dysfunction were ripe for efficient, targeted intervention. Yet the system would have to be designed to support this extra burden. From the ground floor up, it would take into account the population's special needs, and not expect teachers to primarily bear the burden. Currently, "teacher accountability" is frequently mentioned, but more rarely is "systemic accountability". Where is the accountability when systems are in place that shovel highly needy, at-risk populations into traditional classroom environments. It is as if schools, teachers and students are set-up to fail.
I would not be as skeptical of educational innovations such as charter schools or online programs, if they were understood in the context of larger socioeconomic issues in education. For many poor parents, online schooling might make the most sense, and be a good fit for their child's needs. For many others, their children's needs may be better served by an environment that can set the bar higher, knowing that students will be able to competently meet it, as opposed to simply being set-up for failure.
I've long thought a rigorous socio-economic assessment regime could be designed that measures and then places families into school settings designed to appropriately meet their specific needs. To me, this is truly what "choice" looks like. It isn't bottom-up, in terms of parents being "allowed" to send their children wherever they like. But that concept assumes that poor families are homogeneous in their ability to best see to their children's development. The reality is that many poor families need top-down help, and giving them "choice" is a false notion, implying that poor performing families are "choosing" not to be successful. Everyone wants to be successful, even the families struggling with poor parenting skills, single-parenthood, substance abuse, etc. But they don't know how. The sad reality is that we only have two choices when it comes to many poor families - the nanny state, or the neglectful parent state. Contrary to the fantasies we would like to believe about human behavior, reality is that, due to the many disadvantages and behavioral constraints besetting poor communities, owing to numerous historical and systemic factors, we are in a position of "parenthood", in that if left to fend for themselves, too many families - and their children - will not be successful. That is the reality. That is the reality of "choice".
Sunday, November 27, 2011
Me and My Brain
As a longtime sufferer of depression, I've relied on pills designed to treat chemical imbalances in my brain. These pills are controversial, with conflicting opinions on whether they are really more effective than placebos. Millions of people swear by them, many claiming that they have clearly been effective in treating their depression. Of course, such data is anecdotal, as would be any that I could offer. I can say anyhow, that my depression has been somewhat reasonably managed for years.
When I first began taking the medication, about seven years ago, I did recall a significant feeling that my conscious state had been altered. Almost impossible to describe, it was as if a kind of numbness came over me, taking "the rough edges" off of things. My psychological history in the subsequent years was complicated. In some ways I did seem to feel a certain sense of relief. Yet a couple of years later, shortly after my first daughter was born, I attempted suicide. I had certainly entered a deeply depressed state, one in no small part induced by geographic and social isolation, as well as the stress of being the primary caregiver for a colicky infant, all while suffering from devastating chronic neck pain.
So in one sense the medication failed me, or at least was not effective enough to prevent suicidal depression. But the trouble with measuring the efficacy of antidepressant medications is that the population being treated suffers from an illness that is very difficult to properly diagnose, properly quantify, and much less understand the pathology of. To what extent was my depression and my behavior driven by brain chemical imbalances, and to what extent was it driven by my habit of mind, or cognitive framing of the world?
Philosophically, the debate over what consciousness is, or to what degree we can understand it, is contentious. Much of conscious human experience is not well understood, and little data exists to support hypotheses as to either what causes it, or what it even is. Thomas Metzinger, director of the Theoretical Philosophy Group and current president of the Association for the Scientific Study of Consciousness, defines consciousness as "the appearance of a world". It is a good start, but doesn't offer much of a clue as to where it comes from or what it in fact is.
There are many phenomena that we can't really explain very well, and yet must start somewhere if we are to hypothesize - especially if there are real-world consequences of our assumptions either way. Critiques of materialism usually see people as assuming too much, relying too readily on a physical framework as a best guess. Critiques of the opposite - immaterialists? - see people as ignoring what seem to be perfectly reasonable logical conclusions drawn from our knowledge of the physical world.
I tend to fall into the latter camp. I'm reminded of the old creationist thought experiment, the clearly "designed" phenomenon in the natural world, such as Mt. Rushmore or a house in a desert, in which physical processes are assumed to be incapable of such complexity. This can be contrasted with a thought experiment designed to illustrate Occam's Razor, where a broken, blackened tree is found in a field - in the absence of clear evidence, one might assume any number of explanations, some more fantastic than others. Yet the most likely, the most reasonable explanation would be that lightening has probably struck it down.
Surely, many biological processes - certainly those involving the brain and/or consciousness - are lacking in a great deal of evidence. But there is also much that we do know, and would be remiss in not taking into full account, if not inferring even further material hypotheses. For my part, I look forward to advances in this exciting area of science. Not only for what medical breakthroughs it might provide in the treatment of psychiatric illness, but for what it might tell us about broader, older philosophical assumptions about human behavior and the social structures they inform.
When I first began taking the medication, about seven years ago, I did recall a significant feeling that my conscious state had been altered. Almost impossible to describe, it was as if a kind of numbness came over me, taking "the rough edges" off of things. My psychological history in the subsequent years was complicated. In some ways I did seem to feel a certain sense of relief. Yet a couple of years later, shortly after my first daughter was born, I attempted suicide. I had certainly entered a deeply depressed state, one in no small part induced by geographic and social isolation, as well as the stress of being the primary caregiver for a colicky infant, all while suffering from devastating chronic neck pain.
So in one sense the medication failed me, or at least was not effective enough to prevent suicidal depression. But the trouble with measuring the efficacy of antidepressant medications is that the population being treated suffers from an illness that is very difficult to properly diagnose, properly quantify, and much less understand the pathology of. To what extent was my depression and my behavior driven by brain chemical imbalances, and to what extent was it driven by my habit of mind, or cognitive framing of the world?
Philosophically, the debate over what consciousness is, or to what degree we can understand it, is contentious. Much of conscious human experience is not well understood, and little data exists to support hypotheses as to either what causes it, or what it even is. Thomas Metzinger, director of the Theoretical Philosophy Group and current president of the Association for the Scientific Study of Consciousness, defines consciousness as "the appearance of a world". It is a good start, but doesn't offer much of a clue as to where it comes from or what it in fact is.
There are many phenomena that we can't really explain very well, and yet must start somewhere if we are to hypothesize - especially if there are real-world consequences of our assumptions either way. Critiques of materialism usually see people as assuming too much, relying too readily on a physical framework as a best guess. Critiques of the opposite - immaterialists? - see people as ignoring what seem to be perfectly reasonable logical conclusions drawn from our knowledge of the physical world.
I tend to fall into the latter camp. I'm reminded of the old creationist thought experiment, the clearly "designed" phenomenon in the natural world, such as Mt. Rushmore or a house in a desert, in which physical processes are assumed to be incapable of such complexity. This can be contrasted with a thought experiment designed to illustrate Occam's Razor, where a broken, blackened tree is found in a field - in the absence of clear evidence, one might assume any number of explanations, some more fantastic than others. Yet the most likely, the most reasonable explanation would be that lightening has probably struck it down.
Surely, many biological processes - certainly those involving the brain and/or consciousness - are lacking in a great deal of evidence. But there is also much that we do know, and would be remiss in not taking into full account, if not inferring even further material hypotheses. For my part, I look forward to advances in this exciting area of science. Not only for what medical breakthroughs it might provide in the treatment of psychiatric illness, but for what it might tell us about broader, older philosophical assumptions about human behavior and the social structures they inform.
Saturday, November 26, 2011
Politics, Language and Thought
As I look at conservative and liberal politicians, pundits and lay commentary, a pattern begins to emerge in which certain attitudes and cognitive "styles" seem to be more common to one side or the other.
The right seems to like certainty - as opposed to nuance, "masculine" forceful presentation and domineering conviction - as opposed to "feminine" softness and passive listening, or "openness". These seem strongly associated with traditional versus progressive social identities.
My guess is that many conservatives might disagree with that framing. Would they see any truth to it, though? Just by looking at the type of personal styles and approaches to governing and speaking, are there any patterns that they might see between liberal/conservative attitudes and personal presentations, especially that have policy consequences?
I think I see evidence for my framing. I also think you can find a lot of the language both partisan sides use that supports it as well. Conservative and liberal citizens seem to have divergent ways they see and talk about the world.
George Lakoff, a liberal linguist who has done much to popularize this discussion, at least on the left, identifies a set of words significant to partisan politics, drawn from speeches and writings. Among conservatives, the following words are given primacy:
I've been reading this paper that looks at how psychologists and sociologists have tried to examine the issue over the past half century. However I'm pretty skeptical of their findings. For instance, they seem to want to suggest that there are personality types that lead to conservative or liberal thinking. Yet the personality types they identify are rather vague: conservatives = more conscientious, liberals = more "open to new ideas". But it would seem that conservative or liberal thinking leads to these dispositions. Furthermore, the tribal, identity-driven aspects of liberal and conservative communities reinforce norms that foster these dispositions. For instance, in one part of the study they cataloged the possessions of self-identified conservative and liberal grad students, and found correlations, such as more liberal students having more ethnic music in their CD collections. Yet are these students really more "open" people, or are they part of a liberal identity that has pushed them to go out and explore ethnic music? This normative pressure may indeed result in them being more "open" to different ideas, either cultural, political, etc., and thus seem to be more "open" people, but it doesn't necessarily tell us anything about an innate personality. Likewise, their findings that conservative rooms tended to be cleaner and have more sports memorabilia would seem to be evidence of conscientiousness and preference for tradition, yet these too are cultural, normative artifacts.
I'm curious how conservatives would see the issue. The psychological and sociological research appears to have been dominated by liberal researchers. Yet there is something to culture, ethnicity, normal and political partisanship. If not innate (likely), there do seem to be quite different normative pressures involved. Especially as society seems to have become more polarized, I think it is an important issue to investigate. As people become more politically polarized, both in community networks and even geographically, these norms would seem to be even more self-reinforcing. There almost seem to be many structural inevitabilities at work. Is this pattern a natural evolution of a heterogenous, democratic, wealthy nation, in which people's natural, tribal inclinations are perpetuated by their ability to self-select into political and cultural tribes?
The right seems to like certainty - as opposed to nuance, "masculine" forceful presentation and domineering conviction - as opposed to "feminine" softness and passive listening, or "openness". These seem strongly associated with traditional versus progressive social identities.
My guess is that many conservatives might disagree with that framing. Would they see any truth to it, though? Just by looking at the type of personal styles and approaches to governing and speaking, are there any patterns that they might see between liberal/conservative attitudes and personal presentations, especially that have policy consequences?
I think I see evidence for my framing. I also think you can find a lot of the language both partisan sides use that supports it as well. Conservative and liberal citizens seem to have divergent ways they see and talk about the world.
George Lakoff, a liberal linguist who has done much to popularize this discussion, at least on the left, identifies a set of words significant to partisan politics, drawn from speeches and writings. Among conservatives, the following words are given primacy:
character, virtue, discipline, tough, strong, self-reliance, self-reliant, individual, responsibility, backbone, standards, authority, heritage, competition, earn, hard, work, enterprise, property, reward, freedom, intrusion, interference, meddling, punishment, traditional, dependency, self-indulgent, elite, quotas, breakdown, corrupt, decay, rot, degenerate, deviant, [and] lifestyle.And among liberals:
social, forces, expression, human, rights, equal, concern, care, help, health, safety, nutrition, dignity, oppression, diversity, deprivation, alienation, corporations, corporate, welfare, ecology, ecosystem, biodiversity, [and] pollution.However, a study of the actual use of these words in political ads failed to find much of a correlation between the identified conservative language and conservative ads. However, there did seem to be a correlation between identified liberal language and liberals campaign ads. The author hypotheses that this need not undermine Lakoff's thesis, but rather illustrate the different dynamics involved in the efficacy of political advertising.
I've been reading this paper that looks at how psychologists and sociologists have tried to examine the issue over the past half century. However I'm pretty skeptical of their findings. For instance, they seem to want to suggest that there are personality types that lead to conservative or liberal thinking. Yet the personality types they identify are rather vague: conservatives = more conscientious, liberals = more "open to new ideas". But it would seem that conservative or liberal thinking leads to these dispositions. Furthermore, the tribal, identity-driven aspects of liberal and conservative communities reinforce norms that foster these dispositions. For instance, in one part of the study they cataloged the possessions of self-identified conservative and liberal grad students, and found correlations, such as more liberal students having more ethnic music in their CD collections. Yet are these students really more "open" people, or are they part of a liberal identity that has pushed them to go out and explore ethnic music? This normative pressure may indeed result in them being more "open" to different ideas, either cultural, political, etc., and thus seem to be more "open" people, but it doesn't necessarily tell us anything about an innate personality. Likewise, their findings that conservative rooms tended to be cleaner and have more sports memorabilia would seem to be evidence of conscientiousness and preference for tradition, yet these too are cultural, normative artifacts.
I'm curious how conservatives would see the issue. The psychological and sociological research appears to have been dominated by liberal researchers. Yet there is something to culture, ethnicity, normal and political partisanship. If not innate (likely), there do seem to be quite different normative pressures involved. Especially as society seems to have become more polarized, I think it is an important issue to investigate. As people become more politically polarized, both in community networks and even geographically, these norms would seem to be even more self-reinforcing. There almost seem to be many structural inevitabilities at work. Is this pattern a natural evolution of a heterogenous, democratic, wealthy nation, in which people's natural, tribal inclinations are perpetuated by their ability to self-select into political and cultural tribes?
Tuesday, November 22, 2011
The Elephant In the Room
To be sure, there is no substitute for a good teacher. There is nothing more valuable than great classroom instruction. But let’s stop putting the whole burden on teachers. We also need better parents. Better parents can make every teacher more effective.I was astonished when I read this quote in today's NY Times. It's from Thomas Friedman, someone you might have little reason to believe would make a claim so far outside the current neo-liberal/conservative alliance on education reform. The full column, titled How About Better Parents?, points out that the real culprit in student achievement is not poor teaching, but poor parenting. This is not a call for breaking the teachers unions, nor a call for higher standards, nor a more market-based emphasis on charter schools and teacher accountability. It is a head-on call for a change in the national debate about what really drives the achievement gap.
Looking through the comments to his piece, one gets the impression that his claim is obvious. Of course it is the parents - we all know this! Yet why does the education reform debate ignore this issue. One the one hand, it assumes that all poor parents need is more choice in where to send their children, as if a better school is all that is needed. On the other hand, it sees schools as the primary factor in student achievement, and thus the solution to closing the achievement gap, and inevitably solving poverty in America.
I think there are two historical reasons for this schizoid thinking, one each from the left and right, and they account for why parenting has been so long ignored. The right has never had a problem with blaming parents. It is the first to blame all social ills on culture and ethnicity (even, at times, genes). Its primary interest, the security of the white middle class against the barbaric poor, not to mention its fear of the secularism of the state, drove it to embrace vouchers as a way to allow middle class families to remove their children from public schools (and the children in them). Yet it found that dropping the issue of vouchers for a much less controversial, yet in many ways similar, call for charters was good politics.
Charters could be promoted without ever having to engage in the sort of victim-blame that was such red meat for the base, yet turned off the majority of American voters. In fact, charters were a sort of win-win: not only were they a way of breaking unions (and big-government democratic ambitions), but they could be held out as quasi free-market solutions to poverty and the achievement gap.
The left, for its part, has never been comfortable with blaming the poor. It's been too busy trying to argue the structural issues with a capitalist economy, as well as fighting for multiculturalism and the right wing notion that other cultures and ethnicities - even immigrants, brown people! - are as important and have as valuable a place at the American table as any. So the idea that the low success rates for poor students can be traced to their poor home environment and lack of quality parenting, and not racism, discrimination, or exploitation, the idea that the poor are to blame for their own lack of academic success, would seem to undermine everything they've always fought for.
Yet this doesn't have to be the case. What both sides are missing is the scope of the problem. While the left wants to ignore the contemporary, active dysfunction among the poor, the right wants to ignore the historical social and economic structures that have conspired to create, and actively perpetuates a population which has been leeched of its human and social capital, and thus its ability to leverage in the world. The children, the students of this population are simply the current inheritors of what is essentially our collective failure to establish an equitable distribution of human and social capital.
My desire is that Friedman's words will not fall on entirely deaf ears. He surely isn't alone. The words he speaks will make intuitive sense to any who reads them. Yet what must be transcended is our fear of embracing a difficult and messy truth about America, both past and present. The problem - nothing less than poverty and social disadvantage itself - has always been humanity's greatest challenge. Solving it will require a serious reckoning not only with what kind of institutions and governmental structures we seek, but, and more fundamentally, with how we perceive human agency itself. This is the elephant in the room.
Sunday, November 20, 2011
Give Us Our Freedom Back
Kevin Drum reflects on a NY Times article on the pattern of economic segregation and polarization over the last few decades.
I don't know that I can do much better. There have obviously been major shifts both in culture and the economy in this period. The right wing explanation for the phenomenon, as usual, avoids structural critiques and pins the blame on secularism, progressive loosening of mores, and well-intentioned yet ill-conceived government interventions, and of course, a basic lack of personal responsibility. Government, it is claimed, has contributed to this breakdown in traditional values by removing moral hazard from personal responsibility, via welfare or other forms of social safety netting.
Charles Murray, darling of the right, and infamous author of the Bell Curve, which argued that some races are genetically superior in IQ to others, thus explaining disproportionate poverty rates, is coming out with a new book on the issue. At a recent talk at the American Enterprise Institute, he expanded upon his thesis. Conservative blogger Roger Selbert outlines Murray's description of the problem:
It isn't at all clear that iIndustrious as measured by declining work hours represents a lack of industriousness. It is a well-known fact that many businesses purposefully limit their employees hours and rely on temporary labor to maximize profits. This has had a devastating impact both on salaries and eligibility for health care.
While religion can be a powerfully motivating and empowering social institution, it can also severely limit free thought, again acting as a bulwark against the dynamism and social progress that is fundamental to economic growth. A strong case can also be made that it is a fairy tale. Useful maybe, but a fantasy nonetheless.
As for honesty, it isn't at all clear that working class people have become less honest. If anything, crime is a function of social debasement and perceived lack of opportunity. Blaming poverty on crime is like blaming a cold on a runny nose.
What seems to be at the root of this analysis his less an attempt to find explanations for rising inequality, and more about an attempt to reinforce and define traditionalist values and identity. Amanda Marcotte speaks eloquently to this authoritarian obsession:
I won't pretend to have any good answers as to why income inequality and geographic and cultural isolation is happening, much less give anything more than an off-the-cuff prescription. But I would begin with looking at human social capital - those elements upon which real social mobility is always leveraged, and then look at structural issues that our system faces. People have not chosen to become less successful, less honest, or less industrious. Marriage as an institution has certainly weakened, but only as horizons for personal identity and ambition have risen. Traditional careers, especially those in low-skill yet high-paying areas of the economy have disappeared. Cultural, social criticism has grown, and people are less credulous. We are less provincial, more expansive, less likely to have as much in common with our neighbors than we once might have. Our system of property values has steadily solidified geographic "classification".
As I said, I'm not comfortable assigning causality, less comfortable prescribing solutions. Yet we can ease these modern burdens: family planning, child care support, better access to health care, cleaner streets, parks, libraries, differentiated public schooling - all paid for with more progressive income taxes. Each of these, while not a solution, is a clear path to increasing the equal distribution of social and human capital. We cannot stop progress, whether for good or ill, but we can strive to fashion it into more of what is really important. Instead of vainly crying for a nostalgic, rosy vision of the past, we must look to our core values of liberty, equality and egalitarianism, and embrace solutions that truly aid in their revivification.
"It was similar in my neighborhood. My father was a university professor. Our neighbor on one side worked at a local factory. Our neighbor on the other side owned a machine shop that made airplane parts. Our neighbor across the street was career Navy. My best friend's father was a Caltrans engineer.He finishes his piece without any suggestions for either what might have caused the problematic phenomenon, or what we might do about it.
"You don't see that kind of thing as much anymore. Today the middle and working class folks have stayed or perhaps moved down, while the dentists and stockbrokers and professors and engineers all live together in upper middle class neighborhoods with great schools and great services. And this self-segregation works in other ways too. I remember reading once that if you have a college degree, the odds are that virtually all your friends do too. So I tested that once. At a party with about 20 of our friends, I mentally went around the room and ticked off each person. Sure enough, all but one of them had a college degree, and about a third had advanced degrees of one kind or another. Given all this, it's hardly surprising that the report finds that 65% of families lived in middle-income neighborhoods in 1970 and today only 44% do."
It's a toxic trend, and it's one that's increasingly reflected not just in our social lives, but in our economic lives and our political lives too. It's not clear what, if anything, can slow it down.
I don't know that I can do much better. There have obviously been major shifts both in culture and the economy in this period. The right wing explanation for the phenomenon, as usual, avoids structural critiques and pins the blame on secularism, progressive loosening of mores, and well-intentioned yet ill-conceived government interventions, and of course, a basic lack of personal responsibility. Government, it is claimed, has contributed to this breakdown in traditional values by removing moral hazard from personal responsibility, via welfare or other forms of social safety netting.
Charles Murray, darling of the right, and infamous author of the Bell Curve, which argued that some races are genetically superior in IQ to others, thus explaining disproportionate poverty rates, is coming out with a new book on the issue. At a recent talk at the American Enterprise Institute, he expanded upon his thesis. Conservative blogger Roger Selbert outlines Murray's description of the problem:
"Marriage: In 1960, 88% of the upper-middle class was married, versus 83% of the working class, a negligible 5% gap. Today, 83% of the upper-middle class is married, but among the working class, marriage has collapsed: only 48% are married. That’s a revolutionary change, as is the percentage of children born to working class single women (from 6% to nearly 50% in the last 50 years).It's hard not to see this outline as a portrait of traditionalist, authoritarian values. If people, it asks, were simply married, more industrious, religious and honest, they would be more successful. What's missing, however, is a larger picture of social and economic realities. While it is true that marriage is a valuable form of social capital, it isn't necessary for life success. Divorce rates have obviously increased, especially among the working class, but this could just as well be explained by an increasing social consciousness and individual cultural independence that fosters dynamism. Think of the added value successful women have brought to the workplace.
Industriousness: The percentage of working class males not in the workforce went from 5% in 1968 to 12% in 2008. Among those with jobs, the percentage working less than 40 hours a week increased from 13% in 1960 to 21% in 2008.
Religiosity: The percentage of Americans saying they have no religion increased from 4% in 1972 to 21% in 2010. A substantial majority of the upper-middle class (58%) retains some meaningful form of religious involvement, whereas a substantial majority of the working class (61%) does not.
Honesty: The great increases in crime and incarceration over the past decades have overwhelmingly victimized working class communities, while hardly touching upper-middle class communities."
It isn't at all clear that iIndustrious as measured by declining work hours represents a lack of industriousness. It is a well-known fact that many businesses purposefully limit their employees hours and rely on temporary labor to maximize profits. This has had a devastating impact both on salaries and eligibility for health care.
While religion can be a powerfully motivating and empowering social institution, it can also severely limit free thought, again acting as a bulwark against the dynamism and social progress that is fundamental to economic growth. A strong case can also be made that it is a fairy tale. Useful maybe, but a fantasy nonetheless.
As for honesty, it isn't at all clear that working class people have become less honest. If anything, crime is a function of social debasement and perceived lack of opportunity. Blaming poverty on crime is like blaming a cold on a runny nose.
What seems to be at the root of this analysis his less an attempt to find explanations for rising inequality, and more about an attempt to reinforce and define traditionalist values and identity. Amanda Marcotte speaks eloquently to this authoritarian obsession:
I won't pretend to have any good answers as to why income inequality and geographic and cultural isolation is happening, much less give anything more than an off-the-cuff prescription. But I would begin with looking at human social capital - those elements upon which real social mobility is always leveraged, and then look at structural issues that our system faces. People have not chosen to become less successful, less honest, or less industrious. Marriage as an institution has certainly weakened, but only as horizons for personal identity and ambition have risen. Traditional careers, especially those in low-skill yet high-paying areas of the economy have disappeared. Cultural, social criticism has grown, and people are less credulous. We are less provincial, more expansive, less likely to have as much in common with our neighbors than we once might have. Our system of property values has steadily solidified geographic "classification".
As I said, I'm not comfortable assigning causality, less comfortable prescribing solutions. Yet we can ease these modern burdens: family planning, child care support, better access to health care, cleaner streets, parks, libraries, differentiated public schooling - all paid for with more progressive income taxes. Each of these, while not a solution, is a clear path to increasing the equal distribution of social and human capital. We cannot stop progress, whether for good or ill, but we can strive to fashion it into more of what is really important. Instead of vainly crying for a nostalgic, rosy vision of the past, we must look to our core values of liberty, equality and egalitarianism, and embrace solutions that truly aid in their revivification.
Tuesday, November 15, 2011
When Freedom Emerges
The free will debate continues in yesterday’s NY Times. The author argues a compatibilist view,
choosing to define free will as
“a set of capacities for imagining future courses of action, deliberating about one’s reasons for choosing them, planning one’s actions in light of this deliberation and controlling actions in the face of competing desires. We act of our own free will to the extent that we have the opportunity to exercise these capacities, without unreasonable external or internal pressure. We are responsible for our actions roughly to the extent that we possess these capacities and we have opportunities to exercise them.”
This framing of the issue has always been somewhat bothersome
to me. Because what he describes is not
actually free will, but rather the process of will itself, the process of
choosing which actions to take. The mere
act of choosing is not necessarily free at all.
My computer makes choices every time I touch the keypad.
Yet what apparently makes choice free is that it be free
from “unreasonable external or internal pressure”. What the heck does that mean? One imagines being forced at gunpoint, or
suffering some physiological imperative.
Yet must we understand the complexity of human thought and feeling in
such black and white terms? We know for
instance, that the unconscious is a profound influence on human behavior. Is the unconscious an unreasonable pressure? We also know that our cognition – the way
that we think, is largely learned and thus limits the structure of our thought. Is that unreasonable pressure?
It seems that what free will really is about is our attempt
to rectify our conscious perception with our ability to choose. We experience ourselves as deliberative
creatures. Yet we know that a vast
degree of our thinking is subjected to unconscious, or cognitively constrained
pressures. The real question is whether
any of our thinking is free from those pressures at all. And considering that it is very difficult to
determine what pressures have been applied to any given conscious thought, we
should have little reason to believe that those thoughts are free at all. We can't simply assume they are free because we don't know much about how they have arisen.
Saturday, November 12, 2011
The Whole Story
Matt Yglesias points out something interesting that is often overlooked when we discuss important people: place. He refers to a concept in the economics of cities known as "agglomeration externalities", "basically the idea that individuals and firms obtain productivity boosts by clustering together." He sees the ways in which a Steve Jobs could not have existed outside of his particular place and time.
In America there seems a curious resistance to this notion of social collectivity. There seems a preference for the vision of solitary genius and individualism. One wonders how much this has to do with the immigrant experience, and the forced severance of connections to our past. Of course, despite the attractive notion of the immigrant going it alone, succeeding on his own merits, this is rather the exception to the rule. The history of immigrant communities is one of networking, cooperation and group goal orientation. Where individuals have succeeded without family help, they have done so despite the odds.
And yet, the fact remains that America is incredibly heterogeneous, with great generational mobility, and a national character defined in no small part by communal isolation. A number of known cognitive biases could contribute to this tendency to see American success in isolation, removed from communal context. A basic impulse of the sentiment could be a desire to deflect the painful experience - the anxiety, the stress - of "going it alone", by remembering events as not just better than they were, but as positively productive. In this sense, one's trials and tribulations are not seen merely as unfortunate handicaps, but actual necessities for personal success.
This is certainly not a valid model of social activity. Success is almost always built from human and social capital resources. To the degree that it is not, more often has to do with good fortune. Now, there certainly is an element of success-inducing tribulation. Being forced to make do with little can be profoundly inspiring of creativity and tenacity. But tribulation alone does not equate with success - that is surely absurd. A crucial component in leveraging tribulation is sufficient human and social capital to allow for both its weathering and subsequent creative transcendence. To a large degree, this capital is formed by an individual's family - how he is raised, but also by community resources and availability of alternative options. Where there is success, no matter how devoid of opportunity an environment may appear at first glance, there will always exist an underlying story of human and social capital.
"As a sophomore in high school, for example, Jobs worked at an electronics store called Haltek that Isaacson describes as “a scavenger’s paradise sprawling over an entire city block with new, used, salvaged, and surplus components crammed onto warrens of shelves, dumped unsorted into bins, and piled in an outdoor yard.” The presence of an excellent electronics stores is helpful to the young Jobs as he builds his skills. But there would be no gigantic electronics specialty store except in a place with an unusually high concentration of people interested in electrical engineering. The presence of the engineers creates the market for the store, which drives the interest of the younger generation of engineers."These patterns exist throughout history. Often emerging organically, serendipitously, they tend to gain their own momentum, as others are attracted to what has become something important. Aside from no small element of happenstance, this process can be best explained by the interaction of human and social capital. In Silicon Valley, individuals with the human capital - the educated, success-minded parents, combined with the concentration of technological resources, created a tinderbox of creativity and enthusiasm for building new technologies.
In America there seems a curious resistance to this notion of social collectivity. There seems a preference for the vision of solitary genius and individualism. One wonders how much this has to do with the immigrant experience, and the forced severance of connections to our past. Of course, despite the attractive notion of the immigrant going it alone, succeeding on his own merits, this is rather the exception to the rule. The history of immigrant communities is one of networking, cooperation and group goal orientation. Where individuals have succeeded without family help, they have done so despite the odds.
And yet, the fact remains that America is incredibly heterogeneous, with great generational mobility, and a national character defined in no small part by communal isolation. A number of known cognitive biases could contribute to this tendency to see American success in isolation, removed from communal context. A basic impulse of the sentiment could be a desire to deflect the painful experience - the anxiety, the stress - of "going it alone", by remembering events as not just better than they were, but as positively productive. In this sense, one's trials and tribulations are not seen merely as unfortunate handicaps, but actual necessities for personal success.
This is certainly not a valid model of social activity. Success is almost always built from human and social capital resources. To the degree that it is not, more often has to do with good fortune. Now, there certainly is an element of success-inducing tribulation. Being forced to make do with little can be profoundly inspiring of creativity and tenacity. But tribulation alone does not equate with success - that is surely absurd. A crucial component in leveraging tribulation is sufficient human and social capital to allow for both its weathering and subsequent creative transcendence. To a large degree, this capital is formed by an individual's family - how he is raised, but also by community resources and availability of alternative options. Where there is success, no matter how devoid of opportunity an environment may appear at first glance, there will always exist an underlying story of human and social capital.